Verified Document

Welfare Reform Term Paper

Welfare Reform Working for wages is the principal means for obtaining income and getting ahead in American society. Work is the key to personal independence and an effective way to achieve a meaningful role in our society. Significant participation in the workforce also is a necessary condition for receiving benefits from our nation's major social welfare programs, unemployment insurance, workmen's compensation, Social Security retirement and disability payments, Medicare health insurance, and the Earned Income Tax Credit. With one major exception, adults living outside of an institution, who are unable to work because of their age, physical condition, or other limitations, must depend on family, friends, and/or a meager patchwork of public relief and private charities for income, food, clothing, and housing (e.g., Supplemental Security Income (SSI), food stamps, general relief, homeless shelters, soup kitchens).

Analysis -- Labor Supply and Demand

Parents of minor children (usually women), whose level of income and assets are sufficiently low to make them eligible for monthly cash assistance authorized by the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) program in the state in which they reside, are the exception to this "work" policy. TANF is a federally funded block grant program that replaced the 60-year-old Aid for Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) program, our nation's only safety net for economically dependent children. TANF is the heart of the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996 (PRAWORA), the welfare reform legislation signed into law by President William Clinton on August 22, 1996 (Blank, 2002). The principal elements of TANF include: limiting to five years the federal government's financial and regulatory responsibility for helping poor families with children, regardless of the cause of their poverty; allowing states to spend their share of federal block grant funds ($16.38 billion annually) in any way "reasonably calculated to achieve the purposes of TANF"; limiting the length of time a family can receive federal cash assistance to five years, with states free to further limit assistance to two years; requiring at least 80% of families receiving TANF benefits to participate in employment activities as a condition for receiving cash assistance or services, hence the term welfare-to-work.

There is general support for the goal of TANF, which is to improve the economic circumstances of the poor through a "jobs" policy. The means chosen for accomplishing this goal is to give more latitude to the states to design programs tailored to fit local needs, including the use of sanctions and the withholding of benefits where needed. With the resources and freedom provided by TANF, it is anticipated that states will develop or expand programs designed to increase the capacity of poor families to be self-reliant and enable them to move into the mainstream of economic life. It is assumed that adult recipients of TANF will be offered job training programs, job placement and search opportunities, and the means to maintain employment through affordable child care, reliable transportation, and other supportive services.

The reduction in welfare rolls that has occurred since the enactment of TANF makes it appear that advocates for welfare reform were correct in their assumptions about what was needed to move AFDC recipients from welfare-to-work. What is not clear is the degree to which TANF and its "jobs" policy will provide a safety net for economically dependent children. Are the children of welfare families better off under the new system? Is there greater or lesser economic security? What happens to children in families when a parent is unable to hold a job in the private sector? What happens if the economy slows down and unemployment rises? Despite its limitations, AFDC nevertheless served two important functions for 60 years, only one of which is incorporated in TANF: (1) AFDC was a transitional income security program for parents of very young children who, after a period of time, were able to move successfully into the workforce; and (2) AFDC was an economic "safety net" for children whose parent(s), for a variety of reasons, was unable to earn wages sufficient to support a family. As an economic safety net, AFDC provided a minimum level of income necessary to support millions of economically dependent children during good times and bad times (Finneran, 2004).

Discussion - Welfare Reform and Public Safety Origins

The history of public welfare in the United States has been one of controversy, change, and continued growth. Prior to the 1900s, local governments shared with private charitable organizations major responsibility for public welfare, or as it was often called, "public relief." As the nation's population increased and the economy became more industrial and urban, the need for relief grew beyond the means, and sometimes the willingness, of local public and private auspices to provide for this populace. State governments assumed progressively more responsibility for the poor. For example, by 1926, 40 states had established some type of welfare program for mothers with dependent children, referred to as "mother's pensions" or "widow's mites."

On...

We now know that welfare reform works." (Woodbury, 2004). Based on the fact that national welfare caseloads have fallen 20% since 1993, the president and others apparently consider reform a success. While any serious analyst would reject this rosy assessment as being premature, it does raise the important question of how to judge the success of welfare reform. This part of the paper takes the view that the success of reform will largely depend on the extent to which former welfare recipients are successfully integrated into the labor market. Will they be able to find work that pays them enough to maintain their already shaky living standards, and to keep it from falling further? Once they find jobs, will they be able to keep them?
Notwithstanding the premature claims of victory, it will be some time before we can begin to know the answers to these questions. It is not too soon, however, to examine the context in which reform is currently transpiring. From the perspective of welfare analysts and policy makers, such an exercise can both help develop a rational set of expectations regarding the outcome of reform and suggest various policies that could lead to a better outcome.

Impacts on Labor-Management Relations

There are a number of ways to generate a set of expectations regarding the impact of welfare reform on employment and wages. One is to apply the rules of comparative statistics, along with accepted labor supply and demand elasticities, to derive estimates of the impact of moving potentially millions of persons from welfare to work. Numerous studies, described in the pages that follow, have used such methods to produce plausible estimates of the impact of the added supply of less-skilled workers on wages and employment. Another way is to describe the current and historical conditions in the low-wage labor market, delineating the various constraints facing workers who are both already earning low wages as well as those coming off of the welfare rolls who are most likely to find work in that sector. The goal of this approach, undertaken in this section, is to try to paint a picture of low-wage labor market conditions and to extrapolate a set of possible outcomes.

New trends in the 1990s

The genuine wage growth in the late 1990s was benefited from across the wage configuration, by low-, middle-, and high-wage earners and by both men and women (see Table A). Salary growth has also been larger among lower-wage employees than among high-wage (or middle-wage) employees, showing a remarkable turnaround from the early 1990s and the former two decades, when low-wage workers not only did worse than other workers but in fact saw their wages continuously decline after inflation (Montgomery, 2004).

TABLE A. Pay and productivity trends, 1990-200

Labor market indicator

Annual growth

Acceleration

1995-2002 vs.

1990-95

(2)-(1)

1990-95

(1)

1995-2002

(2)

Labor productivity

1.4%

2.5%

1.1%

Average hourly:

Wages

0.6%

2.7%

2.0%

Compensation

0.6

1.8

1.3

Real hourly wages*

Men

Low

-0.9%

1.7%

2.6%

Middle

-1.1

1.3

2.4

High

0.1

1.8

1.7

Women

Low

-0.3%

2.0%

2.3%

Middle

-0.3

1.4

1.7

High

0.7

1.9

1.2

*Measured as 20th, 50th and 90th percentiles.

Source: www.census.gov

Moreover, the attributes of jobs have improved remarkably since 1995. The share of workers with employer-provided health insurance -- a clear dividing line between a "good" and a "bad" job -- has grown since 1995, reversing the downward slide in health insurance coverage during the 1980s and early 1990s. The growth of part-time jobs relative to full-time jobs slackened, to the point that there were proportionately fewer voluntary part-time workers in 2002 than in 1995.

Impact -- Trends and Future

Demographic change, as in the shift to single-parent families, has been held to be a major determinant of poverty since the 1970s, when this shift was occurring most quickly (Gimble, 1991). But this conventional wisdom is incorrect. While family structure changes have led to higher poverty rates over the years, their role has diminished over time, and other factors, such as more education (which has led to less poverty) and the growth in inequality (which has increased poverty rates over time) have been quantitatively more important than changes in family structure in determining the rate of poverty. Economic trends have, of course, played a primary role in poverty trends. Over the 1980s, growth was slower, the labor market never tightened up as it did in…

Sources used in this document:
Works Cited

1. Blank, Rebecca M. "Evaluating Welfare Reform in the United States." Journal of Economic Literature 40, no. 4 (December 2002): 1105-1166.

2. Finneran, Lisa, and Morgan Kelly. "Social Networks and Inequality." Journal of Urban Economics 53, no. 2 (March 2004): 282-299.

3. Gimble, Daniel E. "Institutionalist Labor Market Theory and the Veblenian Dichotomy." Journal of Economic Issues 25, no. 3 (September 1991): 625-649.

4. Hillard, Michael, and Richard McIntyre. "Is There a New Institutional Consensus in Labor Economics?" Journal of Economic Issues 28, no. 2 (June 2005): 619-629.
Cite this Document:
Copy Bibliography Citation

Related Documents

Welfare Reform: Necessary and Prudent
Words: 1461 Length: 4 Document Type: Essay

Another main point that authors Grogger and Karoly point out is the fact that the samples used to help build and implement the 1996 welfare reform, specifically the TANF legislation, were skewed in their representation of specific demographics (66). As the need for welfare affects different groups, the need for reform grows out of the necessity to better serve the populations in need. As the 1996 welfare reform events fade

Welfare Reform Act the Word
Words: 854 Length: 3 Document Type: Essay

Several institutions had been affected consequent to the Welfare Reform Act. The U.S. health program, Medicaid, has been created in order for families with a lower income to receive medical assistance. After the enactment of the Welfare Reform Act, several people that earlier enjoyed the services of Medicaid could no longer do so. The Welfare Reform Act had replaced the AFDC program with the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families program (TANF).

Welfare Reform -- Temporary Assistance
Words: 1634 Length: 5 Document Type: White Paper

In other words, that limit should be raised (or exemptions should be allowed) so that the person getting a job and experiencing the pride and increased self-esteem that goes with it, should not have to lose the other supportive components (like food stamps and health insurance for the children's needs) just because now she is making a bit over the limit that was set. Of course it would be

Welfare Reform What Exactly Is
Words: 3094 Length: 8 Document Type: Term Paper

The number of years for eligibility was decreased, and this led to more people being eligible for welfare. Employers were able to increase their labor demand, and the reforms made sure that the increased labor supply would be mandated, at least to a certain extent. (Bradshaw, 2003) These were the overall objectives and aims of the welfare reforms, at a glance, in a hospital setup: to reduce the incapacity benefit

Welfare Reform in His Book
Words: 571 Length: 2 Document Type: Term Paper

Jenck's criticisms do apply to Olasky's arguments concerning the need for personal and local involvement in charity and aiding the poor, though to a lesser degree. Olasky argues in the Tragedy of American Compassion that welfare and other social programs perpetuate poverty because they do not demand any self-help from the recipients, which is similar to Murray's argument that the benefits for remaining poor in a welfare state outweigh the

Welfare Reform From Welfare to
Words: 905 Length: 3 Document Type: Research Proposal

The long-term results are that lower income and working class families are suffering more from these transformations. ("Illinois Economic Outlook," 2012) (Clary, 2012) Once this theory has been supported or refuted, is the point that actuaries can begin to show how the PWORA is impacting stakeholders. ("Illinois Economic Outlook," 2012) (Clary, 2012) ("Illinois," 2013) Statement of the Problem Describe the nature of the problem / policy The state of Illinois is facing a

Sign Up for Unlimited Study Help

Our semester plans gives you unlimited, unrestricted access to our entire library of resources —writing tools, guides, example essays, tutorials, class notes, and more.

Get Started Now