¶ … Unemployment on Voter Turnout Rates in Britain's Elections
In many countries where voting is a right but not compulsory, voter turnout levels have declined precipitously in recent years, causing a growing number of political scientists to examine the effects of various variables on these rates. By contrast, in countries where voting is compulsory such as Australia, Belgium and Italy, voter turnout levels approach 100% (Forman, 2002). The research on political behavior to date has analyzed a wide range of variables that affect voter turnout positively (such as mail ballots or electronic voting from home) or negatively (such as poll taxes or voter identification requirements) (Childers & Binder, 2012). There has been far less research, though, concerning the potential impact of other variables such as employment status on voter turnout levels. For example, Incantalupo (2015) emphasizes that, "At present, gaps exist in our understanding of how unemployment affects political attitudes and behavior in part because there has been so little attention paid to unemployment as a personal hardship and the disparate contexts in which someone can experience unemployment" (p. 4). In fact, it has been more than 30 years when unemployment levels were high since scholarship was focused on unemployment and theories of unemployment were created and evaluated (Incantalupo, 2015), a gap that the proposed study will help fill as discussed further below.
Background and Overview
The importance of voter turnout has become the focus of a growing body of research as a result of differing rates of political participation by various economic and political groups (Schur & Shields, 2002). This research has built on an original study by Downs in 1957 that described the expected utility theory of voting as affecting voter turnout levels. According to Nicholson and Miller (1993), "In its original form, this theory posits that decisions to vote hinge on two factors: the probability that a single vote will affect the outcome of an election and the costs associated with voting" (p. 199). Since the likelihood that a single vote will have an impact on the outcome of an election, many citizens may not vote because the benefits of their voting are discounted compared to the costs that are involved (Nicholson & Miller, 1993).
From Downs' (1957) perspective, it is frequently more "rational" for citizens to not vote because they will have little impact on an election's outcome. In this regard, Abramson and Diskin (2007) note that, "Although the cost of voting is low, the probability that a single voter will affect the outcome in a large election is negligible. Rational citizens, realizing that their probability of affecting the outcome is negligible, may choose to abstain" (p. 501). Downs (1957) conceptualized his theory with the following equation:
R = (B)(P) -- C + D
In this equation, R is the total reward a citizen will gain after voting, B is the benefit one thinks he or she will accrue from having his or her preferred candidate win in an election, P is an individual's perception of the probability that his or her vote will change the outcome of an election, C is the cost associated with voting in terms of time, money and other resources, while D is the psychic satisfaction an individual would gain from voting. If R is positive, the individual is likely to gain a reward from voting that outweighs costs. Hence, the more positive R is, the more likely citizens are to vote.
According to Harder and Krosnick (2008), this equation set forth above illustrates the so-called "paradox of voting" (p. 526). The paradox of voting holds that, "Voting yields benefits only when supported by collective action, so most people should never pay the costs because their effort will never ensure the acquisition of benefits" (Harder & Krosnick, 2008, p. 526).
The results of a study by Incantalupo (2015) identified a relationship between unemployment and voter turnout. Based on his analysis of the effects of unemployment on voter turnout, Incantalupo (2015) reports that, "The economic and social contexts in which [voters] experience unemployment structure the ways in which their economic situations influence their political behavior" (p. 3). Interestingly, the results of this study identified a negative relationship on voter turnout levels and low unemployment rates and a positive relationship between voter turnout levels and high unemployment levels (Incantalupo, 2015). In this regard, Incantalupo (2015) adds that, "Broadly speaking, personal experience with involuntary unemployment is a mobilizing phenomenon that increases voter turnout in high-unemployment contexts and a demobilizing phenomenon that decreases voter turnout in low-unemployment contexts" (p. 3).
Voter...
Big Data Faris (2013) speculates as to whether NSA leaks will compromise big data's future. The article, published on the website Dataversity, notes that there is public concerns about data leaks at NSA. Consumers are becoming more aware about just how much of their information is available to the government. The author calls into question the dichotomy of private data and public data, in particular were corporate entities are gathering data,
Our semester plans gives you unlimited, unrestricted access to our entire library of resources —writing tools, guides, example essays, tutorials, class notes, and more.
Get Started Now