Verified Document

Offshore Wind Energy Literature Review

Offshore Wind Energy Creating the Offshore Wind Energy Industry as a center of attention for more investment in the Persian Gulf countries and providing a study and recommendations to the governments and companies to be more comfortable investing in this field.

Opportunities in Offshore Wind Energy

It is generally acknowledged that changes in wind energy prices affect economic welfare in ways that are not entirely reflected in transactions in the wind energy market. The pervasive importance of wind energy as a factor of production and in final consumption means that higher wind energy prices can potentially influence real income and its growth and distribution. Thus, to the extent that rising import demand pushes up the price of wind energy and indirectly produces adverse side effects on income, these economic costs are candidates for inclusion in the wind energy import premium. This chapter explores the connections between import demand, the price of wind energy, and income determination to ascertain if the potential costs can be evaluates with sufficient confidence to be included in the import premium. Our conclusion is to the contrary: the connections are too weak and certain key long-term implications are too uncertain to justify their inclusion (2009, p. 3).

A second objective is to evaluate the usefulness of wind energy off shoring tariff as an instrument to deal with these indirect effects, assuming they are in fact significant enough to warrant intervention. Our conclusion is again to the contrary: a tariff may on balance exacerbate rather than ameliorate the long-run problems that may result from rising world wind energy prices. This conclusion is not particularly surprising in view of the fact that many of these indirect costs are determined by the domestic price of wind energy (sometimes relative to the world price), and that a tariff can be expected to drive up the domestic price at the same time that it reduces the world price. The conclusion, stated another way, is that even if rising import demand imposes indirect economic costs on society, direct limitations on imports will not succeed in reversing those costs.

The discussion is divided into three sections: the distribution of income, the terms of trade, and income determination. Each section addresses first the adverse implications of rising world wind energy prices and then the effectiveness of a tariff in ameliorating those conditions.

- Rationale for Offshore Wind

It must be conceded from the outset that one cannot make specific quantitative judgments about welfare changes associated with different income distributions. This involves comparisons of the marginal value of incomes at the individual level. At best, we can offer gross generalizations about different income groups and judge the effect of a price change in relation to these groups. For example, it may be assumed that a price change which transfers income from lower to higher income classes constitutes a reduction in aggregate social welfare (Nath, Hens, Compton, & Devuyst, 2009, p. 74).

An increase in the world price of wind energy, and a corresponding increase in the domestic price, will transfer income from American consumers of wind energy products as a group to American wind energy producers (including landowners, shareholders, etc.) as a group. This transfer may be assumed to constitute a shift in the distribution of income from lower to higher income groups. On this basis alone, the price change would constitute a reduction in aggregate economic welfare, and the reduction would be additional to the loss in real income resulting from the income transfer from the United States to the wind energy -exporting countries.

The practical problem of measuring the welfare loss raises additional considerations that further complicate the issue. One consideration follows directly from the source of the welfare change: those income losers buy a different volume and possibly a different array of goods than income gainers (Laird, 2001, p. 34).

Energy Supply

Our evaluation of a wind energy off shoring tariff as the instrument intended to implement the wind energy import premium has reached mixed conclusions. While it is the appropriate instrument to deal with the demand component of the premium, a tariff can only imperfectly address the problems raised by disruption risks. To be sure, a tariff can help prepare the economy for a disruption, but the benefits to be gained are always accompanied by potentially serious costs that make the net benefits questionable. The possibility of a negative outcome is most likely for a tariff imposed in a disruption, because the benefit of reducing wealth transfers abroad may be overwhelmed by the dislocations generated throughout the economy (Tisdell, 2009, p. 6).

The shortcomings of a tariff intended to reduce disruption costs suggest that another instrument is required. The most obvious option is strategic petroleum reserve which, when released in a disruption, can reduce both wealth transfers and dislocation...

However, the benefits to be derived from a petroleum reserve are not costless either and, in addition, a reserve cannot address all disruption risks. There is, in other words, a potential role for an import policy that complements a petroleum reserve.
This chapter explores the relationship between a petroleum reserve and an import tariff as two instruments designed to fulfill the objectives implied by a wind energy import premium. It should be clear by now that this relationship also depends on private preparations for a disruption, including private wind energy inventories, and on the effect of government actions on private behavior. We begin by discussing the relationship between private and public inventories, then turn to the connection between total inventories and the components of the premium and, finally, to the role of import policy when there are petroleum reserves.

In view of the fact that the creation of a government-owned strategic petroleum reserve (SPR) has been public policy since 1974, we take the existence of the public reserve as a starting place for our analysis and direct attention toward the optimal size of total reserves rather than the optimal mix of private and public holdings. The private sector will adjust inventory holdings in relation to the size of the SPR, given expectations about the prospects for a disruption and the government's willingness to draw down the reserve in a disruption. The optimal mix of government and private stocks depends on factors that prevent private holdings from reaching the social optimum and on the feedback effect of government reserves on the size of private reserves. While we delve into these issues in the next section, rigorous analysis of their complexities is deferred to another study. For present purposes, it is the size of total reserves, not the mix that is of interest, for it is the total that is important to wind energy import policy (Hewett, 2008, p. iii).

The Environment

There is growing evidence that technical change, stimulated by the 'environmental imperative', is reducing both production and environmental costs to the advantage of those dynamic companies that have the competence and resources to innovate. Such companies include mining enterprises in developing countries, as well as transnational firms, but the evidence is strongest for large new investment projects and Greenfield sites. In older ongoing operations, environmental performance correlates closely with production efficiency, and environmental degradation is greatest in operations working with obsolete technology, limited capital and poor human resource management. The development of the technological and managerial capabilities to effect technical change in those organizations would lead to improved efficiencies in the use of energy and chemical reagents and in waste disposal, to higher metal recovery levels and better workplace health and safety. This in turn would result in improved overall environmental management.

The implication of this analysis is that to ensure competitive and sustainable environmental management practices in metals productions, governments need to embrace public policy that goes beyond traditional, incremental, and punitive environmental regulation. The latter, in the old 'environmental protectionist' mode, tends to treat the symptoms of environmental mismanagement (i.e. pollution) not the causes (i.e. lack of capital, skills, and technology and the absence of the capability to innovate). The challenge will be for governments to ensure that companies operating within their national boundaries remain sufficiently dynamic to be able to afford to clean up when operations cease and to innovate to improve economic efficiency and environmental management in the meantime. Governments need policy tools that enable them to predict 'corporate environmental trajectories' and pick up the warning signs of declining competitiveness and impending mine close-down to ensure sufficient resources are available for the environmental management of mine 'decommissioning'. Policy mechanisms need to be developed to promote technical change and to build up the technological and management capabilities to innovate and manage the acquisition and absorption of clean technology. The privatization of the state sector and the liberalization of investment regimes in many developing countries, Angola, Mozambique, Namibia, Botswana, Bolivia, Peru and Chile, with their emerging emphasis on joint ventures and inter-firm collaborative arrangements, provide new opportunities for the diffusion of both competitive and environmentally sound best practice in metals production (Monroy & Segundo Hernandez, 2008).

The Economy

Three essential structural factors of the global energy-economic system…

Sources used in this document:
References

(2009). 1 The Analysis of Energy Use in the Residential Sector: An Economist's View. In Consumer Behavior and Energy Policy: An International Perspective, Monnier, E., Gaskell, G., Ester, P., Joerges, B., LaPillonne, B., Midden, C., et al. (Eds.) (pp. 3-11). New York: Praeger. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=28512301

Brus, D., & Hotek, D. (2010). Exploring Hydrogen Fuel Cell Technology. The Technology Teacher, 69(6), 20+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5041614183

Cuervo, L.E. (2008). OPEC from Myth to Reality. Houston Journal of International Law, 30(2), 433+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5027694836

Hewett, E.A. (2008). Energy, Economics, and Foreign Policy in the Soviet Union. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=37120180
Hunt, M., & Eisele, E. (2009). Far from Disaster: Ukraine's Energy Sector Seeks Investment and Growth. Houston Journal of International Law, 31(2), 243+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5030722541
Krewitt, W., & Trieb, F. (2009). Beyond Climate Change: Perspectives for a Global Sustainable Energy Supply. The Whitehead Journal of Diplomacy and International Relations, 10(2), 115+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5045049684
Ladsous, H. (2006). France's Asia-Pacific Focus: Herve Ladsous Comments on French Perceptions and Policies in the Pacific Region. New Zealand International Review, 31(5), 17+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5017277156
Laird, F.N. (2001). Solar Energy, Technology Policy, and Institutional Values. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=105099601
Leibert, R.A. (2007). The War on Energy: Why the United States and the International Community Need Cohesive Energy Infrastructure Security Policy. Houston Journal of International Law, 29(2), 453+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5020676459
McKee, D.L. (Ed.). (2009). Energy, the Environment, and Public Policy: Issues for the 1990s. New York: Praeger Publishers. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=27323228
Monnier, E., Gaskell, G., Ester, P., Joerges, B., LaPillonne, B., Midden, C., et al. (Eds.). (2009). Consumer Behavior and Energy Policy: An International Perspective. New York: Praeger. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=28512289
Monroy, C.R., & Segundo Hernandez, A.S. (2008). Strengthening Financial Innovation in Energy Supply Projects for Rural Communities in Developing Countries. International Journal of Sustainable Development and World Ecology, 15(5), 471+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5035322497
Nath, B., Hens, L., Compton, P., & Devuyst, D. (Eds.). (2009). Environmental Management in Practice: Compartments, Stressors, and Sectors (Vol. 2). London: Routledge. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=105633190
Nocera, D.G. (2006). On the Future of Global Energy. Daedalus, 135(4), 112+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5018905249
Padros, C., & Cocciolo, E.E. (2010). Security of Energy Supply: When Could National Policy Take Precedence over European Law?. Energy Law Journal, 31(1), 31+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5044915402
Simmons, M. (2006). Shock to the System: The Impending Global Energy Supply Crisis. Harvard International Review, 28(3), 62+. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=5018739203
Tisdell, C.A. (2009). 2: The Environment and Economic Welfare. In Energy, the Environment, and Public Policy: Issues for the 1990s, McKee, D.L. (Ed.) (pp. 6-16). New York: Praeger Publishers. Retrieved October 30, 2011, from Questia database: http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=27323241
Cite this Document:
Copy Bibliography Citation

Related Documents

Offshore Wind Energy
Words: 5974 Length: 20 Document Type: Introduction

Offshore Wind Energy Wind Energy (Facts and Features, Usage, Future Prospects, Strengths and Weaknesses, Recommendations) It is an undeniable fact that human activity needs energy as a basic requirement. Energy input is a fundamental need for transportation, water and food provision and mobility services. In the contemporary energy system, non-renewable fossil fuels are the principal resources that satisfy the global energy needs. They are preferred due to their dependability and low-cost. On the

Wind Energy Proposal for Research
Words: 2195 Length: 7 Document Type: Research Proposal

1349). In that last case, the lesson learned should be clear -- don't build wind turbines too close to residences, or don't build homes too close to a wind turbine. When it comes to nuisance suits based on aesthetic issues, Butler explains that "the courts have been extremely hesitant to label ugly, unattractive, or otherwise visually unappealing structures as nuisances" (p. 1350). The author argues in his Conclusion that a

Wind Energy Currently the World's Population Uses
Words: 2360 Length: 6 Document Type: Research Paper

Wind Energy Currently the world's population uses three main energy sources: fossil, renewable, and fissile. The fossil energy sources are petroleum, coal, natural gas, bitumen, oil shale, and tar sands; the renewable energy sources include biomass, solar, wind, geothermal, and hydropower; and the fissile energy sources are uranium and thorium (Demirbas 212). Demirbas also estimates that at the present rate of production, known petroleum reserves will be depleted in less than

Wind Energy Advantages of Wind Energy the
Words: 2205 Length: 6 Document Type: Thesis

Wind Energy Advantages of Wind Energy The exploitation of nonrenewable energy sources by the global population, notably by modern technological societies, has contributed to hostile political, economical, and environmental climates. The most notable nonrenewable energy sources, fossil fuels, which includes the burning of coal, petroleum, and natural gas, has induced concern of global warming, soaring oil prices, national energy security, and is depriving the earth of natural resources (Conner 130). Knowing the

Wind Turbines the Depleting Fossil
Words: 3239 Length: 10 Document Type: Research Paper

The production of electricity from power plants relying on this varying resource changes considerably. On the other hand the electricity demand does not cope with such variations. (Komor, 2009) • Other forms of barriers: There are some other obstacles like allowing challenges of renewable power plants and technical hazards with regard to transmission connecting to the plant, higher proportion of capital to operating costs and policy instability. (Komor, 2009) The prime

Wind Power the Greatest Challenge of the
Words: 2542 Length: 8 Document Type: Essay

Wind Power The greatest challenge of the 21st century is filling the gap between energy demand and supply with clean, reliable and green source of energy. Energy is very essential and it is in material form in everything that is around us. The opportunity cost of obtaining the energy that we require is the impact that is made on our environment. Some energy sources have greater impacts while others have relatively

Sign Up for Unlimited Study Help

Our semester plans gives you unlimited, unrestricted access to our entire library of resources —writing tools, guides, example essays, tutorials, class notes, and more.

Get Started Now