Equilibrium and Barriers
Barriers to Entry and Long-Term Equilibrium in Monopolistic Markets: Strategy and Market Forces
Introduction Marginal Equilibrium
Barriers to entry can arise out of natural market forces as well as through careful strategic creation or enhancement by incumbent organizations that have a great deal of control over a given market and/or industry. When a specific organization has established a monopolistic or near-monopolistic control over its market and enjoys a great deal of stability and equilibrium with some price flexibility as well, it can be very much in its interest to erect or encourage barriers to entry that thwart the possibility of other entrants into the market, disrupting this equilibrium. As mentioned, many of these barriers to entry arise on their own out of market forces, but they can also be encouraged by strategic decisions within incumbent organizations that influence the market generally and at times explicitly.
Before examining how these barriers can be achieved and strategically employed, however, an understanding of how equilibrium is achieved is necessary. Assuming that supply and demand in a given market remain on a constant curve -- which generally also implies a constant price structure and is only achievable n practice when competition is limited -- a firm will reach a state of marginal equilibrium, where marginal costs are equal to marginal revenues (Baumol & Blinder 2008). That is, the organization will reach a production level at which the added cost of producing additional units -- the marginal cost of a given number of units -- is equal to the additional revenue that the sale of these units will generate, meaning no net gain -- no profit (Baumol & Blinder 2008).
Under the neo-classical theory of economics, the state at which marginal costs are equal to marginal revenues is known as market equilibrium; increases in supply by the production of even one more unit cause a price shift that eliminates any profits generated form that production, and/or production costs to produce a single extra unit are equal to the revenue that can be generated at a current price, and a change in price would create a shift in the overall supply-demand curve (Baumol & Blinder 2008). Thus, without producing this extra, non-profit-generating unit, the company has achieved its profit maximization and expends no unnecessary energy, time, or resources on activities that do not generate profits. This state of equilibrium is ideal for most companies, but is achievable only in situations of long-term equilibrium, and these can be sustained by the strategic introduction and enhancement of barriers to entry that keep other firms from introducing market-changing competition.
Market Barriers and Equilibrium
There are many different kinds of market barriers, including different types of barriers to entry as well as barriers to exiting a market, and these all help to establish a market equilibrium by quickly winnowing down a market to its viable players and quickly establishing pricing levels given relatively fixed terms within the market (Bernanke 2003). When a company benefits from a complete long-run market equilibrium, as do monopolistic corporations in their enterprises, maintaining barriers to both entry and exit (which can often become one and the same thing, as shall be explained) is in their best interests.
Microsoft is one key example of how barriers to entry help to maintain equilibrium. With (as of 2003) ninety-percent of all desktop computers sold in the world running on a Windos operating system, Microsoft's market dominance was a major barrier to entry in and of itself (Bernanke 2003). Microsoft was -- and is -- able to control the price of its products and retain higher than normal profits in a state of basic equilibrium because it is so difficult for new entrants to gain any sizeable market share. The publishing world and indeed all industries involving intellectual property benefit from barriers to entry that are government-enforced: copyrights (Bernanke 2003). Making the reproduction of intellectual property illegal except...
Firm, Labor Markets, and Imperfect Information Economics Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition A perfectly competitive market does not have barriers to entry or exit and is characterized by many producers and many consumers, all of whom are price takers -- a term that means the suppliers and the buyers cannot effect the price as they do not have market power ("Competitive Markets," 2014). Monopolistic competitive markets are do have some barriers to
Economics of Alchohol Abuse Alcohol for consumption is not a necessary food item, but for some has become a standard part of adult culture. Increasing the level of alcohol consumption, however, moves from an economic paradigm to a social issue due to the ancillary health and behavioral effects from alcohol abuse. In turn, this becomes part of economics in that it requires fiscal resources to treat societal issues caused by alcoholism:
This also implies inadequacies in fiscal sustainability, which influences investments in private sectors. The second channel happens through the level, composition and quality involved within the public investment, which shows the level at which the public investment replaces the private investments (Schmidt- Hebbel, Serven, & Solimano, 1996). The final channel regards the level of taxation on the corporate earnings and the rules applicable in depreciations. There have been arguments that fiscal policy
The deal was immediately criticized as anti-competitive by William Kennard, the chairman of the Federal Communications Commission, and by the Communications Workers of America, which represents some workers at both of the merged companies. But neither government regulators nor union bureaucrats will have the slightest impact on the latest merger. They have neither the power nor the desire to oppose the plans of the giant telecommunications monopolies. More substantial opposition
The manufacturers are merely consulted; their influence is very limited. In the end, once the price is set, they can only decide if they are willing to sell at that price or not. Take it or leave it. * the combinations of the factors above will put pressure on the pharmaceutical companies to expand geographically as quickly as possible, in order to maximize their chances of recovering their R&D costs
The implant is inserted into the ear and is discarded at slaughter, thus, it does not enter the human food chain (Primer pp). The hormone in the implant is released into the bloodstream very slowly ensuring the concentration of the hormone remains relatively constant and very low (Primer pp). Moreover, the prescribed dosage is the level "which produces the maximum economic response in the animal -- the law of
Our semester plans gives you unlimited, unrestricted access to our entire library of resources —writing tools, guides, example essays, tutorials, class notes, and more.
Get Started Now