Return to Table of Contents or go to next section of interim report.
Date created: August 29, 2006
Last updated: September 11, 2006
NISTIR 7323 - the Determinants of Success in R&D Alliances
Part 2 - Theoretical Perspectives on R&D Alliance Success
The theoretical perspectives underpinning hypotheses tested in this study are derived from both our review of prior literature on R&D alliance success, and from our exploratory interviews with participants in R&D alliances that received funding support from the Advanced Technology Program (ATP) at the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST). We conducted semi-structured interviews that focused on the question: What are the factors that contribute to, or inhibit, alliance success? The participants in these interviews consistently identified factors that related to knowledge sharing in the alliance, which in turn affected success in achieving technical objectives, generating research outcomes, and commercialization of technology (Dyer and Powell, 2001). Drawing on prior research and on these interviews, we developed the theoretical logic and hypotheses presented in the following sections.
Alliance Design Factors: Alliance Structure
Number of Alliance Partners
In alliance design, firms that initiate an alliance aim to optimize the number of partners to involve in the alliance. Additional partners may bring additional knowledge and resources to the alliance, but each additional partner also brings additional transaction and coordination costs (Gulati and Singh, 1998). Each additional partner firm must be included in negotiations regarding the goals of the collaboration, protection of intellectual property, control and ownership of research output, how to share knowledge and collaborate in R&D, etc. Adding more partners to an alliance may also hinder knowledge sharing by increasing the risk of unintended knowledge leakage (Oxley and Sampson, 2004). The greater the number of partners in an alliance, the more reluctant individual firms may be to share knowledge, fearing greater potential for unintended knowledge spillovers when more firms have access to the knowledge.
With each additional partner, the number of alliance partners increases linearly as N, but the number of dyadic relationships increases quadratically as N (N-1)/2. With two firms there is one relationship to manage; with three firms there are three relationships; with four firms, six relationships, and so on. In our interviews with R&D alliance participants, many observed that knowledge sharing and coordination was more difficult with more members. As one participant stated, "The more people you have, the more people you have to coordinate. It gets unwieldy at some point." (Dyer and Powell, 2001, p.14). Above some threshold number of partners, transaction and coordination costs become significant, and concerns about knowledge leakage inhibit the ability of alliance partners to share knowledge, which is critical to R&D alliance success. In the cost-benefit calculation for deciding how many partners to include in an alliance, if alliance designers err in optimizing the number of partners to involve, we expect that the tendency is to underestimate transaction and coordination costs. Hence, we expect that alliances with a greater number of partners will have lower performance outcomes.
Hypothesis 1: The greater the number of R&D alliance partners, the lower the performance outcomes of the R&D alliance.
Presence of Competitors
Prior research suggests that R&D alliances are fraught with risks because firms must simultaneously share knowledge and technology, as well as protect knowledge (Hamel, 1991; Oxley and Sampson, 2004). Firms must find the right balance between maintaining open knowledge exchange to further the technological goals of the alliance while also preventing unintended leakage of knowledge. Preventing opportunism within R&D alliances is a prime concern, and especially challenging for a number of reasons.
First, joint R&D often requires high levels of investment in complementary assets or knowledge by the participants. When a firm performs part of a research project, the knowledge it gains may be useless unless combined with the work of partner firms with complementary knowledge. This creates potential for opportunistic behavior on the part of partner firms that possess the complementary assets or knowledge. In effect, these knowledge assets are "transaction-specific" assets, and in this transaction relationship there is significant potential for opportunism (Klein et al., 1978; Williamson, 1985).
Second, R&D alliances are characterized by a high degree of uncertainty regarding both inputs and outputs. Monitoring inputs and "effort" on the part of one's partner is extremely difficult. R&D alliance tasks are largely intellectual in nature and, therefore, third party monitoring is inefficient. Under these conditions, effective self-monitoring (Demsetz, 1988) is required because it is impossible to really know whether an alliance partner is truly sharing its most relevant knowledge. In short, the high degree of uncertainty regarding inputs and outputs provides numerous opportunities for opportunistic behavior...
In this case, individuals are entitled to produce goods and services to meet their human need instead of private profit (Wolff, 2012). Prevention for Power and Privileges under Social Contract: While social contract provides power and privileges to all members of the society, ordinary people are usually prevented from executing the power and privilege that they are entitled to through various ways. Some of these ways include the state's legitimacy claims
Also, a very liberal strategy like the one that Mexico took after the NAFTA agreements is dangerous to a newly independent state. Extreme liberalization worked well for Mexico because a large and confident Mexico felt like it could benefit greatly from increased trade and labor transfer with the United States, without being pushed around in the agreement, and Canada helped to maintain neutrality. The Joyan Islands, on the other
Republicans construed Obama as suggesting government bailouts for new industries, or at the slightest a more lively federal government function in generating or supporting jobs -- concepts abominations to a lot of conservatives. The Obama campaign countered the idea as political spin that does not replicate the president's feeling or meaning, pointing to full circumstances of the quotation as confirmation (Koch, 2011). Discuss the process of how a Bill becomes a
(Vancketta, 1999) The 'Changes' clause enables the Government "to make unilateral changes to the contract during performance, so long as those changes fall within the contract's scope." The Standard 'Changes' clause utilized in fixes price supply contracts allows the CO to make changes in writing to: 1) the drawings, designs, or specifications when the item is being specifically manufactured for the government; 2) the method of shipment or packing; or 3) the place
Lobbyists may accost legislators to directly influence their vote on a certain issue. Lobbyists fulfill the important role of providing information for legislators' decision-making, educating and forming public opinion, and even contributing to and testifying to certain legislations. Lobbyists are mostly involved in the electoral process through the use of political action committees (Magleby et al.). Creating the Constitution The original framers designed the Constitution for ordinary people who were not
Higher taxes for example relates to less income for basic needs. In terms of political ideology, it is obvious that the particular ideology of the government would affect the rest of the country. In terms of the United States, for example, the Republican government has a certain set of ideals in terms of issues such as abortion, religious ideology, and so on, that they tend to impose upon the population. In
Our semester plans gives you unlimited, unrestricted access to our entire library of resources —writing tools, guides, example essays, tutorials, class notes, and more.
Get Started Now