Company Background
Adidas was formed in Herzogenaurach, a town in Mittelfranken, north of Nürnberg, not far from Erlangen, and remains headquartered there today. The company was founded by Adi and Rudolf Dassler. The brothers eventually had a falling out, with Rudolph founding Puma. Adidas has grown to become one of the leading designers and marketers of sports apparel, footballs, and other related items. The company operates globally, has revenues of nearly €20 billion, and profits of €0.72 billion in 2015 (Adidas 2015 Annual Report).
Adidas competes against Nike, Reebok, Puma, and several other brands in this space. Major product lines include footwear, apparel, and footballs. Adidas sponsors a lot of athletes and athletic clubs as part of its marketing. Ultimately, this industry is characterized by incremental changes to basic product designs, a strategic emphasis on marketing spending, and distribution, and companies that utilize a global strategy, selling the same way in each country in which they operate.
There are a few ways in which the global strategy manifests. First, when Adidas and its competitors seek out endorsement opportunities, they typically look to global opportunities – football stars and clubs are the best opportunities, but other major club sports, and the Olympics are also prime opportunities for sponsorships. Adidas and its competitors seek to differentiate based on branding, and to win markets through superior marketing and distribution. Thus, for Adidas, market entry anywhere in the world is necessarily going to focus on distribution and marketing. Production will not change, but the company will need to choose between global and local marketing, for example.
The Industry
The global athletic footwear and apparel industry is highly competitive, and very large. There are a handful of dominant companies in this industry, but there are also a number of local companies. The typical structure in most countries is that the global brands like Nike, Adidas, Reebok, Puma, etc. are at the high end of the market. They sell high quality, well-designed goods at premium prices, and carry with them a certain amount of prestige that derives from marketing. The rest of the market may be filled with discount brands, usually local. These are produced in the same countries, but to a lesser standard, lack high-end design, and are sometimes made with cheaper materials. These companies seek to capture share at the low end of the market. It is worth noting that in the world's major economies there is not much room in the market for discount brands, as the vast majority of consumers can afford the premium global brands. 'The premium global brands compete around the world. They are the market dominators in the developed world, where competition can be intense because the market is basically a zero sum game, save for incremental economic growth. The developing world forms an entirely different competitive dynamic. The premium global brands not only compete with each other for share, but they also work to grow the size of the market overall. Success in these countries is not just about winning versus other global brands, but about tapping into the economic growth of the country. As such, the economic growth potential of the market in question is one of the key variables that a company like Adidas takes into consideration, when making a market entry decision. The competitive landscape is also relevant, just not as much as in the developed world.
Literature Review
The main approach by which Adidas' decisions will be evaluated will be the transnational approach. At its heart, this approach reflects a company that operates across borders – one that is not quite fully global, but is sufficiently global that it has in many respects lost its tether...
Whether or not Adidas fits this description is a matter for debate. Internally, how it is run, Adidas is still very much a Germany company. But its products, marketing, and production are certainly transnational in nature. Given that these are the key areas where Adidas operates in new markets – in terms of market entry – a case can be made that the transnational framework makes sense here.
Alcacer, Dezso & Zhao (2013) discuss the factors that contribute to MNE location decisions. They begin by pointing out that most of the existing literature focuses on firm location and characteristics on location choices, and that these variables may have insufficient explanatory power with respect to how transnational enterprises make location decisions. After all, these decisions are inherently marketing decisions, so while home country location will certainly play a role, there are clearly going to be other factors. They argue that there are oligopolistic tendencies in industries characterized by transnational competition. This is certainly the case in athletic footwear and apparel – operating at the transnational scale is inherently limiting and there are very few companies that can compete at that level. This by its nature creates a de facto oligopoly, save for the presence of low-end competitors that form an entirely different rung on the competitive ladder.
These authors examine what they consider the three primary equilibrium strategies, avoid, collocate and stronger-chases-weaker. Avoidance is fairly evidence – seeking out markets where there is less competition. We know that in a true oligopoly there are few opportunities for profit, but if a company can find a market where no such competition exists, it can extract monopoly rents, at least temporarily. Collocation sees companies entering the same markets at roughly the same time – there is no particular competitive advantage extended in this situation, but rather it is an extension of the pre-existing oligopoly. Stronger-chases-weaker is basically the natural continuation of the avoidance strategy. A company that is extracting monopoly rents in a market can expect the dominant players to enter that market, bringing to that market the oligopoly conditions that exist elsewhere.
Nachum and Song (2011) argue a couple of things. First, they argue that different forces influence expansion versus contraction for MNEs. Then, accepting this proposition, they explore how the different businesses in which a company operates will influences its market entry decisions. If one thinks about how this applies to the athletic footwear and apparel industry, a company that specializes in soccer might prefer to focus attention on nations where that sport is most popular. As an example, such a company might prefer to target Brazil among the BRICS because soccer is the dominant sport there. It is not a particularly major sport in China or India, so even though those countries are much larger than Brazil, they would not be the first choice market. South Africa might be the weakest of the BRICS for a company specializing in soccer – while soccer is a very popular sport there, this is mainly among poorer people who might prefer cheaper tekkies.
An MNE, Nachum and Song point out, can be viewed as a portfolio of businesses, and those businesses have interdependencies. In this business, those interdependencies will typically manifest in the distribution side. While marketing different products may be siloed, distribution will not be in most places, so whether there is a good fit with existing businesses, or whether there is opportunity to develop a portfolio of businesses instead of just one might dictate market entry choices. In the above example, the soccer-forward company trying to choose between China and India for market entry would look at…